Element | Value | Category / Params / Notes | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Clock | | \(t\) | Ordinary Aging. T=615. \(t\lt 61\) in school | |||
CCP | \(\ln z\) | \(\sim\) | \(N(\tilde{w},\sigma^2)\) | OneDimensionalChoice | ||
Actions | \(\al\) | \(=\) | \((a)\) | Binary Choice | accept offer. | |
States: | \(\th\) | \(=\) | \((h,m)\) | h: IIDBinarym: LaggedAction | has offer accepted in \(t-1\). |
|
Choice Sets | \(CC(\th)\) | \(=\) | \((!m)h\,\&\,t\lt 115\) | condition to solve for \(z^\star\) | ||
\(A(\th)\) | \(=\) | \(\cases{ \{0\} &\)!h\(\cr \{0,1\} &\)CC(\th)\(\cr \{1\} &\)(!m)h\, \&\, t\ge 115\(\cr}\) | no offer has offer, can choose must accept offer | |||
Utility at \(z\) |
\(PDV(z)\) \(U(z)\) | \(=\) \(=\) | \({ z+\delta_v^{T-t}\over 1-\delta_v}\) \(\left(\matrix{ -c \cr PDV(z) }\right).\) | lifetime value of offer | ||
Exp. Utility | \(E_w\) \(EU\) | \(=\) \(=\) | \({\tilde w}\exp\{\sigma^2/2\}\) \(\left(\matrix{c \cr PDV(E_w\lambda/p)}\right)\) |
Expected wage offer see \eqref{EU} | ||
Utility | \(U()\) | \(=\) | \((1-m)(-(1-h)c\) \(+ hPDV(E_w))\) | Non-choice state |
\)
m\( is included in the state vector to indicate that a job was accepted the previous period and decision making ends. To mark a value \)m=1\( as terminal simply requires:m -> MakeTerminal(1);
Second, as discussed earlier in 4.2, a state involves a reservation value if it satisfies \)
\(CC(\th) =(t\lt T+k)\ \&\ h\ \&\ (1-m).\nonumber\)\( At other states the searcher has no choice: they either have no offer to reject or they must accept any offer. This is achieved by providing a replacement for the virtualContinuous()
method with one that returns the logical condition:
SchToWork::Continuous() { return (I::t < T+k) && CV(h) && (1-CV(m)); }
The estimates use a discount rate of \)
\delta = 0.999\(, but the original text states for the long post-search period a "annual discount rate of 5 percent" was used. In weekly terms this results in a discount factor of \)\delta_v = e^{\ln(.95)/52} = .99901408.\(The searcher gets the full present value of wages upon acceptance. This is consistent with the model since there are no further decisions after a wage is accepted. If further decisions that depend on the accepted wage were made then a discrete approximation to its distribution would have to be tracked as a discrete state variable.
The target of the replication are predicted hazard rates reported in Wolpin (1987). A hazard rate is the same as averaging \)
P^{\,\star}(1)\( conditional on not terminating yet (\)m=0\(). The paper grouped the hazard by weeks which requires some additional code. The table of predicted hazards in the original paper and the replicated results are given in 3.The results are substantially different. Starting from the bottom, we see the replicated hazard is about one-fifth that of the reported values. The difference falls as we move back in time to the point that the initial replicated hazard is only 10% below the reported value. This first hazard includes in-school search. The computed reservation wages are for the most part negative. Given log-normal offers this implies all offers are accepted. And after week 54 all offers must be accepted if still searching (by assumption). Together this means that, except near week 1 in the table, the declining hazards simply reflect the falling offer probability not a change in rejection rates.
The differences remain unresolved with 3. The original text (Wolpin 1987 p. 812) notes negative reservation values. Given the need to calculate expected values entering this period while iterating backwards it is important to handle negative values carefully. That is, when \)
w^\star\( is on the support of offers it is possible to use \)w^\star\( to compute \)v(0)\(, the value of rejection. This should receive 0 weight in the calculation because \)Prob(w\le w^\star)=0\( when offers are log-normal and \)w^\star\lt 0.$ Numerical issues in these computations from the 1980s may explain the discrepancy with modern calculations.Weeks i | Reported | Replicated |
---|---|---|
1 | .313 | .2773175 |
2-13 | .141 | .08758 |
14-26 | .135 | .0825763 |
27-39 | .127 | .0690007 |
40-52 | .117 | .0577042 |
53-65 | .105 | .0545755 |
66-78 | .097 | .0445571 |
79-91 | .090 | .0355048 |
92-104 | .083 | .028323 |
105-117 | .076 | .0228554 |
118-130 | .070 | .0186378 |
131-143 | .064 | .0153897 |
144-156 | .059 | .0127247 |
157-166 | .054 | .0107464 |
Predicted hazard rates out of job search at estimated parameters. |
Public methods | ||
Continuous | ||
EUtility | ||
FeasibleActions | ||
PDV | ||
Poff | static | |
Replicate | static | |
Utility | ||
Uz | Return vector of utilities at the cutoff(s) z. |